Áñ°Üã±â Ãß°¡     ½ÃÀÛÆäÀÌÁö·Î ¼³Á¤ óÀ½À¸·Î  l  ·Î±×ÀΠ l  È¸¿ø°¡ÀÔ  l  »çÀÌÆ®¸Ê

>
ȸ¿ø°¡ÀÔ   l   ¾ÆÀ̵ð/ºñ¹Ð¹øȣã±â
¡®Á¦38ȸ 2023³â »ó¹Ý±â ...
¡®Á¦37ȸ 2022³â ÇϹݱâ ...
Á¦37ȸ ¡¸2022³â ÇϹݱâ ...
 
HOME > ÇؿܽÃÀåÁ¤º¸ > ÃֽŴº½º
[2014] [¹Ì±¹] ¼öÁú¹èÃâ±ÇÀ¸·Î Àú·ÅÇÑ ºñ¿ë¿¡ °­ ¿À¿° ÁÙÀÏ ¼ö ÀÖ´Ù´Â ¿¬±¸°á°ú
À̸§ °ü¸®ÀÚ waterindustry@hanmail.net ÀÛ¼ºÀÏ 2014.10.01 Á¶È¸¼ö 478
ÆÄÀÏ÷ºÎ
[¹Ì±¹] ¼öÁú¹èÃâ±ÇÀ¸·Î Àú·ÅÇÑ ºñ¿ë¿¡ °­ ¿À¿° ÁÙÀÏ ¼ö ÀÖ´Ù´Â ¿¬±¸°á°ú

Duke ´ëÇб³¿¡¼­ ½Ç½ÃÇÑ »õ ¿¬±¸¿¡¼­ ¿À¿° ¹èÃâ ´ç»çÀÚ·Î ÇÏ¿©±Ý ¼öÁú ¹èÃâ±Ç(water-quality credits)À» ±¸¸Å, ÆǸŠ¹× ±³È¯ °Å·¡ÇÒ ¼ö ÀÖµµ·Ï ÇØ ÇÏõ À¯¿ª ¹× Çϱ¸ ÅðÀûÁöÀÇ ¿À¿°À» ºü¸£°Ô Àý°¨½Ãų ¼ö ÀÖ´Ù´Â °á°ú°¡ ¹ßÇ¥µÆ´Ù.
¼öÁú°Å·¡ ÇÁ·Î±×·¥À» ÅëÇØ Á¡Á¡ ³ô¾ÆÁö´Â ¿À¿° ÄÁÆ®·Ñ ºñ¿ë¿¡ Á÷¸éÇØ ÀÖ´ø ½Ã¼³µéÀº ±×µéÀÇ ½ÃÀå¿¡¼­ ´Ù¸¥ ¿À¿°¹èÃâ ´ç»çÀÚ(polluter)·ÎºÎÅÍ ¿À¿°Àý°¨±ÇÀ» ±¸¸ÅÇÔÀ¸·Î½á ½º½º·Î ±ÔÁ¦ Á¤Ã¥À» ÃæÁ·½Ãų ¼ö ÀÖ°Ô µÆ´Ù. ±× °á°ú ¼öÁúÇâ»ó ¼öÁØÀº °°À¸³ª, ±×°ÍÀ» À§ÇØ µéÀÌ´Â ½Ã°£°ú ºñ¿ëÀÌ Àý°¨µÇ´Â È¿°ú¸¦ ¾ò¾î³Â´Ù.
 
[¿ø¹®º¸±â]
 
Water quality credits cut river pollution at low cost, research shows
    
A new study led by Duke University has found that allowing polluters to buy, sell or trade water-quality credits could significantly reduce pollution in river basins and estuaries faster and at lower cost than requiring the facilities to meet compliance costs on their own.
 
In water-quality trading programs, facilities facing higher pollution control costs are allowed to meet their regulatory obligations by purchasing pollution reduction credits from other polluters in their trading market. The end result -- improved water quality -- is the same, but the time and money needed to achieve it is less.
 
However, the scale and type of the trading programs, though critical, may matter less than just getting them started. "Our analysis shows that water-quality trading of any kind can significantly lower the costs of achieving Clean Water Act (CWA) goals," said Martin W. Doyle, professor of river science and policy at Duke's Nicholas School of the Environment.
 
"All other things being equal, regulators should allow trading to occur at the river basin scale as an appropriate first step. Larger spatial scales may be needed later if abatement costs increase," said Doyle, who also serves as director of the water policy program at Duke's Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions.
 
To conduct their analysis, Doyle and his team developed a coupled hydrologic-economic model that measured the impacts of one-for-one trading and trading ratios among wastewater treatment plants in river basins draining into North Carolina's Albemarle-Pamlico Sound, the nation's second largest estuary.
They assessed the pros and cons of each program type over the entire length of the basins, not just downriver or in the estuary. They also looked at how costs were affected when market scale was expanded from sub-basin to basin-wide, and then to a larger area that included adjacent basins extending into Virginia.
 
"As the markets got larger, facilities had more opportunities to find suitably-sized trading partners who could help them reduce compliance costs," Doyle said. "But as we exceeded the basin scale, we reached a tipping point where risks increased so that pollution from many sources could end up in just a few places, creating pollution hotspots."
 
The study found only modest differences in the effectiveness of programs allowing one-for-one trading versus trading ratios. The optimal scales of markets remained the same under either scenario. In addition to demonstrating that basin-wide trading is the optimal initial scale for many markets, the team's findings reinforce the need for interstate trading, Doyle said.
 
"Look at a map of the United States. If we are going to have water-quality trading here, we are going to have to allow interstate trading because of the geography of our states and river basins," he said. "Pollution doesn't start or stop at state borders." Doyle is planning future studies to see if the same approach works for reducing non-point-source pollution from urban and agricultural runoff, which is a bigger problem in many river basins.
 
[Ãâó = Water World / 2014³â 9¿ù 24ÀÏ]
¨Ï±Û·Î¹ú¹°»ê¾÷Á¤º¸¼¾ÅÍ(www.waterindustry.co.kr) ¹«´ÜÀüÀç ¹× Àç¹èÆ÷±ÝÁö
ÀÌÀü±Û [ÀϺ»] °³¹ßÀÌ ±Þ¼ÓÇÏ°Ô ÁøÇàµÇ´Â Áß¼Ò ¼ö·Â ¹ßÀü
´ÙÀ½±Û [¹Ì±¹] °¡¹³ Çö»ó¿¡¼­ ¼öµµ°è·®±â°¡ È¿°úÀûÀÎ ¹° °ü¸®¿¡ ´õ¿í ÇʼöÀûÀ̶ó´Â ¿¬±¸ ¹ßÇ¥
±Û·Î¹ú¹°»ê¾÷Á¤º¸¼¾ÅÍ.   ¼¾ÅÍÀå : ¹èö¹Î
ÁÖ¼Ò : ¼­¿ï½Ã ¼ÛÆı¸ »ïÀüµ¿ 72-3 À¯¸²ºôµù 5Ãþ TEL (02) 3431-0210   FAX (02) 3431-0260   E-mail waterindustry@hanmail.net
COPYRIGHT(C) 2012 ±Û·Î¹ú¹°»ê¾÷Á¤º¸¼¾ÅÍ. ALL RIGHT RESERVED.